الكينزية العسكرية

(تم التحويل من Military Keynesianism)

الكينزية العسكرية Military Keynesianism، هو الوضع الذي ينبغي على الحكومة فيه زيادة الإنفاق العسكري بهدف زيادة النمو الاقتصادي. يستخدم المصطلح عادة بشكل سيء للإشارة إلى السياسيون الذين يرفضون الاقتصاد الكينزي، إلا عندما يدعون لخلق وظيفة إيجابية للإنفاق العسكري.[1][2][3]

يدعو الكينزيون إلى أن إنفاق الحكومة ينبغي أن يستخدم في المقام الأول لأغراض نافعة مثل استثمارات البنية التحتية، لكنه حتى لو كان الإنفاق غير مفيداً إلا أنه قد يكون كذلك أثناء الركود الاقتصادي. يدعو جون مينارد كينز إلى استخدام الانفاق الحكومية "في مصلحة السلام والازدهار" بدلاً من "الحرب والدمار".[4] ومن أمثلة مثل هذه السياسات ادارة الأشغال العامة في الثلاثينيات بالولايات المتحدة. But where Keynes advocated increasing public spending on socially useful items (infrastructure in particular), additional public spending is allocated to the arms industry, the area of defense being that over which the executive exercises greater discretionary power. Typical examples of such policies are Nazi Germany, or the United States during and after World War II, during the presidencies of Franklin D. Roosevelt and Harry S. Truman. This type of economy is linked to the interdependence between welfare and warfare states, in which the latter feeds the former, in a potentially unlimited spiral. The term is often used pejoratively to refer to politicians who apparently reject Keynesian economics, but use Keynesian arguments in support of excessive military spending.[5][6][7]

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

علم الاقتصاد الكينزي وتطبيقه

The most direct economic criticism of military Keynesianism maintains that government expenditures on non-military public goods such as health care, education, mass transit, and infrastructure repair create more jobs than equivalent military expenditures.[8]

Noam Chomsky, a critic of military Keynesianism, contends that military Keynesianism offers the state advantages over non-military Keynesianism. Specifically, military Keynesianism can be implemented with less public interest and participation. "Social spending may well arouse public interest and participation, thus enhancing the threat of democracy; the public cares about hospitals, roads, neighborhoods, and so on, but has no opinion about the choice of missiles and high-tech fighter planes." Essentially, when the public is less interested in the details of state spending, it affords the state increased discretion in how it spends money.[9]


ألمانيا النازية

Much of the Third Reich economy was oriented towards militarization, especially to prepare for a possible war with the Slavic nations, rather than in the production of consumer goods or towards commercial expansion. Nevertheless, the concentration of capital in the arms industry had favored a rapid expansion of German industrial capacity and helped to reduce unemployment rates.

الولايات المتحدة

In the United States this theory was applied during the Second World War, during the presidencies of Franklin Delano Roosevelt and Harry Truman, the latter with the document NSC-68. The influence of Military Keynesianism on US economic policy choices lasted until the Vietnam War. Keynesians maintain that government spending should first be used for useful purposes such as infrastructure investment, but that even non-useful spending may be helpful during recessions. John Maynard Keynes advocated that government spending could be used "in the interests of peace and prosperity" instead of "war and destruction".[4] An example of such policies are the Public Works Administration in the 1930s in the United States.

رسالة كينز لرزوڤلت 1933

In 1933, John Maynard Keynes wrote an open letter to President Franklin Roosevelt urging the new president to borrow money to be spent on public works programs.[4]

Thus as the prime mover in the first stage of the technique of recovery I lay overwhelming emphasis on the increase of national purchasing power resulting from governmental expenditure which is financed by Loans and not by taxing present incomes. Nothing else counts in comparison with this. In a boom inflation can be caused by allowing unlimited credit to support the excited enthusiasm of business speculators. But in a slump governmental Loan expenditure is the only sure means of securing quickly a rising output at rising prices. That is why a war has always caused intense industrial activity. In the past orthodox finance has regarded a war as the only legitimate excuse for creating employment by governmental expenditure. You, Mr President, having cast off such fetters, are free to engage in the interests of peace and prosperity the technique which hitherto has only been allowed to serve the purposes of war and destruction.

بارني فرانك

While the idea dates back to Keynes, a similar term is often attributed to بارني فرانك، and seems to have been first used around funding the F-22 fighter:[7][10]

These arguments will come from the very people who denied that the economic recovery plan created any jobs. We have a very odd economic philosophy in Washington: It’s called weaponized Keynesianism. It is the view that the government does not create jobs when it funds the building of bridges or important research or retrains workers, but when it builds airplanes that are never going to be used in combat, that is of course economic salvation.

أشكال

The following forms of military Keynesianism may be differentiated:

  • First, there is the differentiation between the use of military spending as 'pump primer', and efforts to achieve long term multiplier effects by the given spending. A government may opt to approve the purchases of fighter planes, warships or other military commodities so as to weather a recession. Alternatively, it may opt to approve the purchase of fighter planes, warships or other military commodities throughout all the years of a given business cycle. Since the construction of large armament systems requires extensive planning and research, capitalist states generally prefer to rely on arms' purchases or other military allocations for longer-term macro-economic policymaking and regulation.[بحاجة لمصدر]
  • A second differentiation that needs to be made is between primary and secondary forms of military Keynesianism. In both cases, the state uses the multiplier mechanism in order to stimulate aggregate demand in society. But the primary form of military Keynesianism refers to a situation where the state uses its military allocations as the principal means to drive the business cycle. In case of a secondary form of military Keynesianism, the given allocations contribute towards generating additional demand, but not to the extent that the economy is fully, or primarily, driven by the military allocations.[بحاجة لمصدر]
  • The third differentiation starts from the observation that modern capitalist economies do not function as closed systems but rely on foreign trade and exports as outlets for the sale of a part of their surplus. This general observation applies to the surplus generated in the military sector as well. As the vast amount of data regarding state promotion of arms' exports do confirm, capitalist states actively try to ensure that their armament corporations gain access to import orders from foreign states, and they do so amongst others in order to generate multiplier effects. Hence, there is a need to also differentiate between the two forms of domestic and 'externalized' military Keynesianism.[5]

اقتصاد الحرب الدائمة

The concept of permanent war economy originated in 1945 with an article by Trotskyist[11] Ed Sard (alias Frank Demby, Walter S. Oakes and T.N. Vance), a theoretician who predicted a post-war arms race. He argued at the time that the United States would retain the character of a war economy; even in peacetime, US military expenditure would remain large, reducing the percentage of unemployed compared to the 1930s. He extended this analysis in 1950 and 1951.[12] In 1974, this idea was expanded on by Seymour Melman in the book “The Permanent War Economy: American Capitalism in Decline” where Melman describes the downside of having a permanent war economy as “sustained nonproductive use of capital and labor.[13]” Melman goes on to observe that because this issue “is not unique to the United States[14]” that “It is shared by all states that try to sustain permanent war economies[15].” Melman argues that most of the military production is unnecessary and drains the talents of highly skilled workers due to politicians attempting to create a powerful influx of jobs in their districts, and because of this, most military production is in place to create jobs instead of adding to public safety. Melman suggests that the large sum of money allocated towards unnecessary military spending would be put to better uses by maintaining or improving domestic infrastructure to have an active positive benefit to society.

التقديرات التجريبية

Many economists have attempted to estimate the multiplier effect of military expenditures with mixed results. A meta-analysis of 42 primary studies with 243 effect size, which are aggregated results from multiple studies, found that military expenditures tend to have positive effects on economic growth in developed countries but generally negative effects on growth in less developed countries. The study attributes the negative effects to the diversion of resources from productive sectors such as education and infrastructure.[16]

التأثيرات الخارجية

Externalities are rarely if ever considered in estimating a multiplier effect. This can be a serious issue for military expenditures. For example, the Islamic State of Iraq and the Levant (ISIL) relies mostly on captured weapons. For example, in Mosul between 4 and 10 June 2014 a group of between 500 and 600 ISIL troops "were able to seize six divisions' worth of strategic weaponry, all of it US-supplied" from a force with a paper strength of 120,000 men.[17][18][19] In considering the multiplier effect of military expenditures, the people killed and property destroyed are not considered. The only things that are considered are the increased weapon sales to replace those stolen and the costs associated with combatting ISIL. Those are considered as increasing the Gross Domestic Product of the United States, and that is assumed to be good.[بحاجة لمصدر]

انظر أيضاً


. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

الهوامش

  1. ^ Custers, Peter (2010). "Military Keynesianism today: an innovative discourse". Race & Class. 51 (4): 79–94. doi:10.1177/0306396810363049.
  2. ^ Veronique de Rugy (December 2012). "Military Keynesians". Reason magazine. Reason Foundation. Retrieved 2 February 2013.
  3. ^ Krugman, Paul (2009-06-24). "Weaponized Keynesianism". New York Times. Retrieved 26 January 2015.
  4. ^ أ ب ت Keynes, John Maynard (1933). "An Open Letter to President Roosevelt". Retrieved 2011-08-01. {{cite web}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help) خطأ استشهاد: وسم <ref> غير صالح؛ الاسم "keynes_letter" معرف أكثر من مرة بمحتويات مختلفة.
  5. ^ أ ب Custers, Peter (2010). "Military Keynesianism today: an innovative discourse". Race & Class. Institute of Race Relations. 51 (4): 79–94. doi:10.1177/0306396810363049. S2CID 154824097.
  6. ^ Veronique de Rugy (December 2012). "Military Keynesians". Reason Magazine. Reason Foundation. Retrieved 2 February 2013.
  7. ^ أ ب Krugman, Paul (2009-06-24). "Weaponized Keynesianism". New York Times. Retrieved 26 January 2015.
  8. ^ Feffer, John (February 9, 2009). "The Risk of Military Keynesianism" (PDF). Institute for Policy Studies (originally in Foreign Policy In Focus).
  9. ^ Noam Chomsky (February 1993). "The Pentagon System". Z Magazine. Reason.
  10. ^ Frick, Ali (2009-06-23). "Barney Frank: GOP Thinks $2 Billion F-22 Project Is Funded By Monopoly Money". Think Progress.
  11. ^ van der Linden, Marcel (2 January 2018). "Edward L. Sard (1913–99), Theorist of the Permanent War Economy". Critique (in الإنجليزية). 46 (1): 117–130. doi:10.1080/03017605.2017.1412629. ISSN 0301-7605.
  12. ^ See Peter Drucker, Max Schachtman and his Left. A Socialist Odyssey through the 'American Century', Humanities Press 1994, p. xv, 218; Paul Hampton, "Trotskyism after Trotsky? C'est moi!", in Workers Liberty, vol 55, April 1999, p. 38
  13. ^ Melman, Seymour (1974). The permanent war economy: American capitalism in decline. New York: Simon and Schuster. ISBN 978-0-671-21811-9.
  14. ^ Melman, Seymour (1974). The permanent war economy: American capitalism in decline. New York: Simon and Schuster. ISBN 978-0-671-21811-9.
  15. ^ Melman, Seymour (1974). The permanent war economy: American capitalism in decline. New York: Simon and Schuster. ISBN 978-0-671-21811-9.
  16. ^ Awaworyi, Sefa; Yew, Siew Ling (2014), The Effect of Military Expenditure on Growth: An Empirical Synthesis, 14, Department of Economics, Monash U., https://business.monash.edu/__data/assets/pdf_file/0004/339475/the_effect_of_military_expenditure_on_growth_an_empirical_synthesis.pdf, retrieved on 2017-03-15 
  17. ^ "5. 2009–2015: Syria uprising and ISIL in Syria", Enemy of Enemies: The Rise of ISIL, 2015 
  18. ^ Astore, William J. (2014-10-14), Tomgram: William Astore, America's Hollow Foreign Legions – Investing in Junk Armies, TomDispatch.com, http://www.tomdispatch.com/post/175907/tomgram%3A_william_astore,_america%27s_hollow_foreign_legions/, retrieved on 2014-10-16 
  19. ^ "2. 2004–2006: Abu Musab Al-Zarqawi Emerges", Enemy of Enemies: The Rise of ISIL, Al Jazeera, 2015 

المراجع

وصلات خارجية

قالب:Macroeconomic schools